本文的重點是介紹我們是否支持收入再分配政策,這個不僅取決于我們的父母是多么富有或我們成長所在的社會等級多么公平(收入的先定因素),也取決于糟糕的運氣、成功以及塑造我們生活的艱難困境(后天的經歷)。Piketty(1995),通過實證文獻證明,我們生活中獲得收入的過程可以完善我們的個人信念,并且可以使我們更加努力的工作,它可以影響我們對未來收入的預期值,進而決定我們對再分配的支持力度究竟有多大。
本文也存在一些不足。我們學習如何從這些生活經歷之中找到可以影響我們可以支持分配財富和解決困難的方法。十年前失業也使財政一度陷入困境,但是它可能推動美國支持重新分配政策,這與去年的失業率措施是不同的。當然我們也遇到很多生活中的苦難,我們不得不減少食品消費,生存與利益比失業更為重要,它的持久性在過去在的十年里有所增加,并且這種增長幅度已超過一年。在本文中,我們分析現像的流動性經歷是如何影響東歐和中亞地區的重新分配政策,在此我們使用的生活經歷調查(分割):第一波(分割)面試的樣本為2.9萬人。
Introduction Whether we support income redistribution depends on not only how well off our parents were or how egalitarian the society we grew up in was (predetermined factors of income), but also the bad luck, the successes, and the hardships that have shaped our lives (mobility experiences). As Piketty (1995) suggests, and the empirical literature confirms, our past mobility experiences refine our beliefs in the relative importance of hard work and luck, which affects our expectations of future income and, in turn, determines our support for redistribution.
The literature is scant, however, on how we learn from these mobility experiences—how the particulars of fortunes and hardships affect our support for redistribution. The timing of hardships, for example, is likely to matter. Being unemployed ten years ago possibly nudges us to support redistribution, but not as much as being unemployed last year does. The intensity of hardships matter too (going through hardships in which we had to cut down on food consumption to survive matters more than being unemployed with benefits), so does its persistence (ten-year unemployment in the past ten years increases support for redistribution more than one-year unemployment does). In this paper, we examine how these particulars of mobility experiences affect support for redistribution in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. We use the Life in Transition Surveys (LITS): The first wave (LITS I) interviews more than 29 thousand individuals in 29.
Upward- or downward mobility as part of society-wide (Piketty, 1995) or own (Benabou and Ok, 2001) future income prospects has been discussed with support from empirical studies. Factors that explain variation in support for redistribution include cultural differences (Alesina and Glaeser, 2004), parents’ influence (Benabou and Tirole, 2005), perception of fairness (Alesina and Angeletos, 2005), and status of social standing (Corneo and Gruner, 2002). 2 In general, theories of fairness judgments (Adams, 1965; Piketty, 1995) suggest that gainers from reforms who believe in hard work and effort are likely to oppose redistribution.
Countries and records their labour-market- and life histories over a period of eighteen years from 1989 to 2006. The second wave (LITS II) records the life history of 39 thousand individuals during the recent global crises in 2007-08. Using these labourmarket- and life histories, we construct measures of intensity, timing, and persistence of personal history of mobility and we examine how these particulars of mobility affect support for redistribution. Countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia offer an interesting case to study how personal mobility affects support for redistribution. These countries were command economies that enjoyed extensive systems for redistribution but had to go through structural reforms, exposing their citizens to economic shocks that are, to some extent, beyond the control of any individual. The states provided education, housing, and healthcare services; citizens enjoyed heavily subsidized basic consumer goods and most people worked for the government or state-owned enterprises (Szelenyi and Kostello, 1996; Mikhalev, 2003). Then, in the early 1990s, most of these countries embarked on structural reforms (they liberalized, among others, price regulation, labour markets, exchange rate regimes, and trade policies), which increased income inequality and unemployment rates. Some skilled workers enjoyed higher salaries and more secured jobs (Gimpelson and Lippoldt, 1996, 1997), but many people not only lost their jobs, but also lost welfare benefits as the states trimmed social safety nets (Kapstein and Mandelbaum, 1997). A new pattern of social stratification emerged: a new elite class (mostly new capitalists), a middle class (people in the managerial and professional job), a lower class.
Some studies show support for redistribution in socialist countries is high, which may be caused by socialist cultural heritage (Corneo, 2001), behavioral norms (Ockenfels and Weimann, 1999), and the direct effect of communism (Alesina and Fuchs-Schuendeln, 2007). Corneo and Gruner (2002) also find, in 1992, Eastern Europeans have stronger support for redistribution than people from Western countries do.
(Mostly blue colored workers), and a socially deprived marginal class (Mikhalev, 2003). Haphazard redistribution of the states’ assets and rising income inequality polarized societies and exposed people in Eastern Europe and Central Asia to diverse personal mobility experiences (Mikhalev, 2003). These mobility experiences varied across time and space. Earlier in the transition period from 1989 until 1995, most of these countries had fallen into recession. Some economies, mostly European Union member states, improved later, but in 1998 a financial crisis hit the Russian Federation and affected most of the Commonwealth of Independent States. However, since the early 2000s, these economies had grown, which improved their citizens’ living standards and reduced poverty rates: The average real per capita income rose from US$5,903 in 1998 to US$8,411 in 2005, moving fifty million people out of poverty (World Bank, 2008). Early but partial reforms created some early winners and losers in some countries. Subsequently, more comprehensive reforms led to even more gainers and losers (Mikhalev, 2003). Since people in these countries have diverse personal mobility experiences, in this paper we examine how these mobility experiences affect support for redistribution. We define support for redistribution, the dependent variable, as an indicator that equals one if an individual thinks that the state should be strongly involved in “reducing the gap between the rich and the poor”. As measures of downward mobility, we use a section on labor market and life histories in LITS I, which includes a set of questions on mobility experiences such as whether an individual had to accept wage cuts in a particular year from 1989 to 2005, whether she had to sell some of her household assets, and whether.
She had to respond to shocks by cutting down food consumption. First, we construct three measures of intensity of mobility experience for each individual and each of the years: (1) whether an individual experienced any type of shocks, (2) whether an individual experienced labor market related shocks only, and (3) whether an individual responded to shocks by taking extreme measures. Then, we summarize each of the measures by adding up the number of years an individual had experienced downward mobility during the seventeen-year period. The measures are, therefore, the number of years an individual experienced downward mobility by intensity. For the timing of downward mobility, we divide the seventeen-year period into several sub-periods and create measures of mobility for each period (a larger estimate of later shocks, which indicates more recent downward mobility, indicates the more recent an individual experienced shocks, the stronger her support for redistribution will be). For the persistence of downward mobility, we create measures of mobility by the number of years an individual experienced shocks (a larger estimate for more frequent shocks indicate the more persistent an individual experienced shocks, the stronger her support for redistribution will be). We use regression-control strategies to estimate the effects of downward mobility on support for redistribution. We include all available individual- and household characteristics in LITS I as well as primary sampling unit (PSU) fixed effects in the regressions, the latter to control for time-invariant determinants of support for redistribution that may correlate with downward mobility. To the extent that downward mobility is exogenous conditional on these individual- and household characteristics and the PSU fixed effects, a regression of support for redistribution on downward mobility.
See LITS (2006) for more details of this survey. We exclude Mongolia and Turkey to focus on the 27 former socialist countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia; we also exclude mobility experiences in 2006 to make sure we examine the effects of past mobility experiences only.
And the control variables provides an unbiased estimate of the effects of downward mobility. We find downward mobility increases support for redistribution, but only the more intensive mobility: One year of downward mobility experience in which an individual had to respond by taking extreme measures increases support for redistribution by about three percent. We also find the timing and persistence of downward mobility matter: recent bad years matter more than earlier bad years do; more persistent bad years matter more too. For example, one bad-year in the last four years during the period of analysis increases support for redistribution by about three times as much as the average effect. Moreover, experiencing nine bad years or more increases support for redistribution by about 12-17 times larger than the average effect. Additional extensions and robustness checks by using alternative measure of support for redistribution, analysing an alternative source of downward mobility (the recent global crisis), considering systematic biases in evaluating individual preferences, and assessing the possibility of omitted variable bias all show that these basic results hold. The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the empirical strategy and data. Section 3 discusses the basic results. Section 4 discusses extensions and robustness checks. Section 5 concludes.
Where yij is a measure of support for redistribution of individual i who lives in PSU j; D is a measure of downward mobility of individual i, X and Z are vectors of individual- and household characteristics, respectively; and ?j and ? ? ? are PSU fixed effects and error terms, respectively. We include all observed individual- and household past characteristics such as individual’s age, gender, education, and household’s size, which may correlate with downward mobility and support for redistribution, to make sure downward mobility is as random as possible. We also include PSU fixed effects to control for PSU time-invariant, both observed and unobserved, determinants of support for redistribution that may correlate with downward mobility such as cultural-specific determinants of support for redistribution and region-specific inclination towards economic reform. To the extent that downward mobility is random conditional on their individual- and household characteristics as well as PSU fixed effects, the coefficient of D in Equation (1) is the effect of downward mobility on support for redistribution. We use the first wave of the Life in Transition Survey (LITS I), a joint initiative of the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the World Bank. LITS I, which is done in 2006, covers 29 countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and surveys a nationally representative sample of 1,000 individuals within each country. The dataset includes household level data such as households’ roster, assets, and expenses. It also has information on the attitude and values, current activities, labour supply, and life history of 29,000 individuals who are chosen at random among adults within each household. We exclude Mongolia and Turkey to focus on the 27 former socialist countries in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. We also exclude mobility experiences in 2006 to make sure we.
Examine the effects of past mobility experiences only. We have, therefore, the labourmarket- and life histories of about 27 thousand individuals for seventeen years from 1989 to 2005. We use individuals’ life history to construct measures of downward mobility. In the survey, individuals are asked whether they experienced some types of hardships, or whether they responded to these hardships by taking extreme measures, in each year from 1989 to 2005. The questions are, among others, whether they received unemployment benefits, had to accept wage cuts, had to sell some of their household assets, and had to cut down on basic food consumption. We construct three measures of the intensity of downward mobility as follows. First, we create three dummies: one, a dummy for whether an individual experienced any types of shocks; two, a dummy for labour- market-related shocks only; and, three, a dummy for shocks that individuals responded to with extreme measures such as cutting down on food consumption or selling household assets to survive—all for each of the years from 1989 to 2005. Then, we summarize each of these three set of dummies by adding them up across all years from 1989 to 2005. Therefore, the three measures of downward mobility intensity are: (1) the number of years an individual experienced any types of shocks during the seventeen-year period, (2) the number of years of labour market related shocks only, and (3) the number of years that an individual responded to hardships by taking extreme measures. To explore how timing and persistence of downward mobility affect support for redistribution, we also use other functions of the above measures of downward mobility.
They are as follows: (1) for the timing we use the number of years and indicators of shocks in two eight-or-nine-year periods or four four-or-five-year period, and (2) for persistence we use indicators of shocks by the number of shocks experienced. Larger estimates of downward mobility for later periods, for example, would indicate that recent downward mobility affects support for redistribution more than downward mobility experienced a long time in the past does. Larger estimates of more frequent downward mobility in a sub-period would indicate persistent downward mobility affects support for redistribution more than occasional mobility does. We define the dependent variable, supports redistribution—an indicator equals one if an individual supports redistribution or zero otherwise—from a question on whether an individual thinks the state should be strongly involved in “reducing the gap between the rich and the poor”. As part of robustness checks, we also use alternative measures: whether an individual thinks the state should be strongly involved in “guaranteeing employment” or “guaranteeing low prices for basic goods and food”, and whether an individual agrees with the statement that “a market economy is preferable to any other form of economic system”. The individual and household characteristics we use as control variables are the number of adults in the household, the number of children in the household, gender, age, relationship to household head, religion, nationality, whether the individual lives in urban areas, whether the individual has college degree, and whether the individual is a member of ethnic minority. In some specifications, we also include individual characteristics in 1989, i.e., whether an individual worked, was rich, trusted people, and believed in efforts in 1989, as well as the father's and the mother’s characteristics in 1989, e.g., whether the father has college degree, a member of communist party, and worked in 1989. To test the robustness of the basic results, we also include current individual and household.
Characteristics in some specifications, i.e., whether an individual worked in 2006, his or her job characteristics, and household's spending in 2006. Each of the control variables enters the regression as a full set of dummies, which makes the model very flexible. (For example, age enters as a set of dummies, one for each age cohort.).
Notes: Each dot represents a country’s average support for redistribution and proportion of individuals in the country that experienced downward mobility; the line is a regression line of the first on the second. Downward mobility is an indicator of whether an individual had experienced shocks and responded by taking extreme measures the 1989-2005 period; supports redistribution equals one if an individual supports income redistribution in 2006 or zero otherwise.
Figure 1 illustrates the relationship between support for redistribution and downward mobility. Each dot represents a country’s average support for redistribution and the We do not include these variables in most of our specifications because these variables can be also outcomes.
Proportion of individuals in the country that experienced downward mobility defined as “responded to shocks by taking extreme measures”. The relationship is noisy, which suggests that other factors affect support for redistribution, but we still see a positive relationship between downward mobility and support for redistribution. That is the relationship that we want to examine after we control for individual and household characteristics to make downward mobility as random as possible. Table 1 shows the summary statistics of the key variables. Individuals who experienced downward mobility, and those who did not, seem to be quite similar in terms of individual and household characteristics (Panel A). A typical household has about three members on average; most of these are adults. About 40 percent of the individuals are males, 47 years old on average, 37 percent live in urban areas, 20 percent has college degrees, and 10 percent are members of minority groups. Their characteristics in 1989 do not seem to differ either (Panel B), neither do the father’s characteristics (Panel C). If anything, those who experienced downward mobility were more likely to work, trust people, and believe in efforts in 1989. There is some evidence that individuals who experienced downward mobility are more likely to support redistribution, though the differences may be insignificant statistically (Panel D). About 38 percent of respondents experienced shocks and responded by taking extreme measures; on average they had about six bad years (Panel E).
No experience of downward mobility (1) A. Individual- and household characteristics Number of adults in the household Number of children in the household Male Age Lives in urban areas Has college degree A member of ethnic minority B. Individual characteristics in 1989 Worked in 1989 Rich in 1989 Trusted people in 1989 Believed in efforts in 1989 C. Father's characteristics Has college degree A member of communist party Worked in 1989 0.13 (0.34) 0.13 (0.34) 0.95 (0.22) 0.12 (0.33) 0.17 (0.37) 0.95 (0.21) 0.52 (0.50) 0.34 (0.47) 0.60 (0.49) 0.78 (0.41) 0.54 (0.50) 0.37 (0.48) 0.69 (0.46) 0.80 (0.40) 2.69 (1.38) 0.45 (0.86) 0.43 (0.50) 47.01 (18.58) 0.37 (0.48) 0.20 (0.40) 0.10 (0.30) 2.71 (1.42) 0.61 (1.01) 0.38 (0.49) 46.71 (16.62) 0.37 (0.48) 0.18 (0.39) 0.11 (0.31) Experienced downward mobility (2)
Notes: The number in each cell is the mean. The figures in parentheses are standard deviations.
Table 1 Summary Statistics (continued)
No experience of downward mobility (1) D. Preferences towards redistribution Supports redistribution 0.67 (0.47) Agrees that state should guarantee employment 0.77 (0.42) Agrees that state should guarantee low prices 0.72 (0.45) Agrees that poverty is because of injustice in 0.44 society (0.50) Does not prefer market economy 0.56 (0.50) E. Downward mobility Number of years experienced shocks and 0 responded by taking extreme measures Household is worse now than in 1989 0 0.55 (0.50) (5.13) 0.66 (0.47) 5.88 (0.50) 0.62 (0.49) 0.51 0.71 (0.45) 0.83 (0.38) 0.78 (0.42) Experienced downward mobility (2)Notes: The number in each cell is the mean. The figures in parentheses are standard deviations.
Empirical Results We now discuss the results. Sub-section 3.1 presents the basic results while sub-sections 3.2 and 3.3 include PSU-fixed effects as well as other control variables. Sub-section 3.4 explores the effects of the timing and persistence of downward mobility on support for redistribution.
Table 2 presents the basic results. Each column is a regression of supports redistribution on downward mobility with or without individual- and household characteristics as control variables, which include gender; age; education; religion; ethnic minority; relationship with household head; whether the household lives in a rural area, urban area or metropolitan city; the number of adults in the household; and the number of children. Columns 1-2 show the estimates of downward mobility, which we define as the number of years an individual experienced any types of shocks, without and with the control variables, respectively. (All estimates are multiplied by 100 for legibility.) Both estimates are significant statistically (robust standard errors, clustered by PSU, are in parentheses) and large economically: One-year experience of shocks increases support for redistribution by 0.3-0.4 percentage point or about 0.4-0.6 percent. (About 68 percent of individuals in the sample support redistribution.) Considering that people who experienced hardships had six bad-years on average, people who experience hardships are 2-4 percent more likely to support redistribution. In columns 3-8 we use two other measures of intensity of downward mobility. Using labor market related shocks only as measures of downward mobility in columns 3-4, the estimates are small and insignificant statistically. But when we use another measure, “responded to shocks by taking extreme measures” in columns 5-6, we find the estimates to be larger than those in columns 1-2 and significant statistically. The estimate in column 6 shows having a bad year increases the likelihood of supporting redistribution by 0.6 percentage point. In the last two columns we include both responded-to-shocks-bytaking-extreme-measures and experienced-labor-market-shocks-only. The estimates of the first remain significant statistically, while those of the second do not. The magnitude of estimates of the first is also similar to that in columns 5-6.
Controlling for PSU fixed effects Support for redistribution varies by country, which suggests that PSU- or country-specific factors affect how people think about redistribution. Grosjean (2011), for example, shows that cultural characteristics such as social trust in European countries evolves very slowly over time and vary across countries by the history of their imperial rule through centuries. Moreover, individuals in different countries experienced different economic reforms, which depend on country-specific politics. Therefore, models we estimate in the previous sections, which ignore country-specific determinants of downward mobility and support for redistribution, may suffer from omitted variable bias. Table 3. Controlling for PSU Fixed Effects.
Dependent variable: Supports redistribution (1) Downward mobility Responded to shocks by taking extreme measures (number of years) Experienced labor market shocks (number of years) Both the above (number of years) Individual- and household characteristics PSU fixed effects Adjusted R.
In Table 3, to control for these time-invariant factors, we include PSU-fixed effects in addition to the individual- and household characteristics. Overall, the estimates are similar to those in Table 2. The estimate of responded to shocks by taking extreme measures is significant statistically; that of experienced labour market shocks only is not, both as the only measure of downward mobility in column 2 and when use jointly with responded to shocks by taking extreme measures in column 4. The magnitudes of the estimates are slightly smaller. The estimates in columns 3 and 4 suggest that, after controlling for PSU-fixed effects, a bad year increases support for redistribution by about 0.4 percentage point. These estimates mean a typical individual who responded to shocks by taking extreme measures is 3-4 percent more likely to support redistribution. The results in Tables 2-3 suggest labour-market-related shocks such as getting unemployed or having a wage cut do not necessarily increase support for redistribution. However, if the shocks are severe so that people have to respond by taking extreme measures such as cutting down on food consumption or selling household assets, experiencing these shocks does increase support for redistribution. In the rest of the analyses, for brevity, we will present the estimates of downward mobility defined as responded to shocks by taking extreme measures only.
Controlling for other characteristics The results are robust even after controlling for the PSU-fixed effects, but because we use control strategy as a method of identification, there is always a possibility that the models suffer from omitted variable bias. Therefore, in Table 4, we include other past individualand parental characteristics as additional controls. In some specifications, we also include.
current individual characteristics such as current job characteristics and household spending to see whether the direct effects of downward mobility on support for redistribution are large. Table 4. Controlling for Other Covariates.
Dependent variable: Supports redistribution (1) Downward mobility Responded to shocks by taking extreme measures (number of years) Individual- and household characteristics Additional individual characteristics in 1989 Individual characteristics in 2006 Worked in 2006 Job characteristics in 2006 Spending in 2006 Income, belief in trust, and belief in efforts in 2006 Father characteristics Mother characteristics PSU fixed effects Adjusted R2 Number of obs.
In column 2 we include individual characteristics in 1989 as additional controls, i.e., job status in 1989, the position along a ten-step economic ladder, the degree of trust in people, and the belief on whether effort and hard work as well as intelligence and skills are the most important to succeed in life. In column 3 we add father characteristics (education level of the father, job status, and whether he is a member of a communist party) further, in column 4 the same set of characteristics of the mother as well. The estimates are 0.4-0.5, similar to that in column 1, which is from a regression without the additional controls. They also remain significant statistically. We then include current individual characteristics in columns 5-7. In column 5 we include an indicator of whether an individual worked in 2006, in column 6 we add job characteristics (a full set of dummies for types of occupations, industry, and whether selfemployed) and the logarithm of household spending in 2006—the estimates do not change much. In column 7 we include a set of individual characteristics in 2006 (i.e., the position along a ten-step economic ladder, the degree of trust in people, and the belief on whether effort and hard work as well as intelligence and skills are the most important to succeed in life). The estimate falls to 0.3 and remains significant statistically. Even after we include individual characteristics in 2006 in the regression, which muddle the estimation of total effects of downward mobility, we still find that downward mobility experiences increase support for redistribution. Table 4 shows that overall the basic results are robust. In all iterations, one bad year increases support for redistribution by about 0.4 percentage points. Even after controlling for current individual characteristics in 2006, the estimates remain large economically and significant statistically, which indicate that downward mobility also directly affects support for redistribution, not only through its effects on current employment status and current beliefs in efforts, hard work, and luck.
In the rest of the analyses, to get the total effects of downward mobility on support for redistribution, we exclude these current individual characteristics as additional independent variables. To keep most individuals in the sample, we do not include the additional individual characteristics in 1989 either.
Support for redistribution on a measure of downward mobility and a set of basic control variables, i.e., gender, age, education, religion, ethnic minority, relationship with household head, whether the household lives in a rural area, urban area or metropolitan city, the number of adults in the household, the number of children, and PSU fixed effects.
Timing and persistence of downward mobility In Tables 2-4 we assume a bad year has the same effects regardless of whether it happened a long time ago and whether they happened consecutively—we ignore the timing and persistence of hardships. In Table 5 we relax this assumption in four ways: (1) we use the number of years an individual responded to shocks by taking extreme measures in two eight-year periods or four four-year periods, (2) we use indicators of shocks by periods, (3) we use indicators of shocks by number of shocks experienced.
These current characteristics are bad controls because they can be also outcomes (Angrist and Piscke, 2009). 10 In column 2, after controlling for additional individual characteristics in 1989, the number of observations falls from 27 thousands to about 19 thousands. After controlling for parental characteristics in column 4, it falls further to 17 thousand observations. 11 Including the additional past characteristics does not change the results. They are available from the authors upon request.
Table 5. Allowing for More Flexible Effects of Downward Mobility
Dependent variable: Supports redistribution A. Number of shocks by periods A.1. Two eight-or-five-year periods 1989-1997 1998-2005 A.2. Four four-or-five-year periods 1989-1993 1994-1997 1998-2001 2002-2005 B. Indicators of shocks by periods B.1. Two eight-or-five-year periods 1989-1997 1998-2005 B.2. Four four-or-five-year periods 1989-1993 1994-1997 1998-2001 2002-2005-0.07 (0.16) 0.87** (0.14) 0.21 (0.32) -0.26 (0.40) 0.47 (0.39) 1.23** (0.31)0.50 (0.77) 3.49** (0.69) 1.77 (0.95) -0.88 (0.99) 1.16 (0.89) 3.85** (0.81).
We actually use two eight-or-nine-year periods and four four-or-five-year periods, but we will call these two eight-year periods or four four-year periods for brevity.
In Panel A we use the number of shocks by sub-period to allow downward mobility early and later in the period of analysis to have different effects. Panel A.1 shows the estimates in which we use the number of bad years by two eight-year periods as the measures of downward mobility. The estimate of the 1989-1997 period is small and insignificant statistically, but that of 1998-2005 is significant. The magnitude of the latter is also large, about 0.9, which equals four percent increase in the likelihood of supporting redistribution by those who experienced hardships in 1998-2005 on average (those who experienced shocks in the last eight year period had 4.3 bad years on average). In Panel A.2 we use four four-year periods. Again similar picture appears: Experiencing shocks early in the period does not seem to matter, while later bad years do. The magnitude of the estimate of the last four year period, 2002-2005, is large, 1.2, which means individuals who experienced shocks in the last four years are four percent more likely to support redistribution (those who experienced shocks in the last four year period had three bad years on average). In Panel B we use a set of indicators instead of the number of shocks as the measures of downward mobility. We see similar results. Experiencing shocks recently increases support for redistribution. The estimate of the last four year period in Panel B.2 in particular is large. Having at least one bad year in 2002-2005 increases support for redistribution by 3.9 percentage points. In Panel C we use indicators of shocks by number of shocks to allow occasional- and persistent shocks to have different effects on support for redistribution. The estimate in Panel C.1 shows that having at least one bad year increases support for redistribution by three percentage points, which is similar to the results in Tables 2-3. In Panel C.2 we introduce three dummies, no shock, 1-8 shocks and 9-17 shocks (the excluded category is no shock). Experiencing eight bad years or less increases support for redistribution by 2.3.
Percentage points, while experiencing nine bad years or more increases support for redistribution by about 5.6 percentage points. In Panel C.3 we include five dummies: no shock, 1-4 shocks, 5-8 shocks, 9-12 shocks, and 13-17 shocks. Similar results appear. Having less than five bad years increases support for redistribution by 1.7 percentage points, while having 9-12 shocks or 13-17 shocks increases support for redistribution by about 5-7 percentage points, which is equivalent to about 7-8 percent increase in support for redistribution. In Panel D we examine whether experiencing mobility changes from one year to another—the ebb and flow of hardships—affect support for redistribution. Including the number of changes of downward mobility from one year to another during the seventeen year period seems to increase support for redistribution, but it is significant statistically at ten percent only (Panel D.1). Once we control for the number of shocks in Panel D.2, however, the number of changes of downward mobility becomes insignificant statistically as indicated by its large standard error. To summarize, these results show that: (1) experiencing at least one-year shocks (defined as responded to shocks by taking extreme measures) in the previous seventeen years increases support for redistribution by three percentage points on average; (2) shocks experienced a long time ago do not seem to matter, while recent shocks do—one bad year in the last four year period increases support for redistribution by 1.2 percentage points; (3) persistent shocks matter more than occasional ones—having at least nine bad years in the 16 year period of analysis increases support for redistribution by more than five percentage points, and (4) the ebbs and flow of downward mobility does not seem to matter once we take into account the intensity of the shocks
Extensions and robustness checks In this section we show some extensions and robustness checks. Table 6 explores the interactions between downward mobility and individual characteristics. Tables 7 and 8 analyse the effects by group of individuals and group of countries. Tables 9 and 10 use alternative measures of support for redistribution and downward mobility. Table 11 examines another source of shocks, the recent economic crisis. Tables 12 consider biased perception of individual’s relative position in income distribution, and Table 13 examines whether unobservable factors undermine the OLS estimations.
Interactions between Downward Mobility and Individual Characteristics Table 6 presents the interactions between individual characteristics and downward mobility. The estimates of downward mobility are positive and significant statistically; they are also quite stable across all specifications. We find that females and non-college graduates are more likely to support redistribution, which are in line with papers in this line of literature. We also find that individuals who are 50 years old or older, those who believed in the importance of effort in determining success in life in 1989, and those who trusted people in 1989 are more likely to support redistribution, which seem to be in contrast with the findings in the literature.
Characteristics in the past, the results are perhaps unsurprising because some people had experienced downward mobility since then and may have changed their beliefs in the importance of effort in determining success and their trust in people in 2006 when the survey was done, which in turn affect their support for redistribution. None of the See, for examples, Fong (2001), Corneo and Gruner (2002), Alesina and Glaeser (2004), Alesina and La Ferrera (2005), and Alesina and Fuchs-Schundeln (2007).
Interaction terms is significant statistically, however, except the interaction between college graduates and downward mobility. Table 6. The Effects of Downward Mobility by Individual Characteristics.
Analyses by Groups of Individuals and Groups of Countries In previous analyses, we implicitly assume the control variables affect different groups of individuals similarly. In Table 7 we relax this assumption by estimating the effects of downward mobility by group of individuals, i.e., gender, older than 50 years, has college degrees, high on the ten-step economic ladder in 1989, a member of ethnic minority, believed in the importance of effort in determining success in 1989, trusted people in 1989, and father was a member of communist party. Overall, the results are robust. All estimates are positive: They vary from 0.2 to 0.6 percentage point. They are also significant statistically except for individuals who were high on the ten-step economic ladder in 1989 and those whose fathers are members of communist parties. There seems to be similar effects across groups, though some groups (i.e., individuals who were older than 50 years, college graduates, low on the ten-step economic ladder in 1989, members of ethnic minorities, and those who did not believe in the importance of effort in determining success in 1989 as well as those whose fathers were members of communist parties) are more likely to support redistribution.
In Table 8 we estimate the effects of downward mobility by group of countries. The largest effect is estimated for the EU countries (0.8 percentage point), and the lowest for non-CIS and non-EU countries (that is, others in column 3). Though the latter remains positive, it is insignificant statistically. Table 8. The Effects of Downward Mobility by Groups of Countries.
Use of Alternative Measures of Support for Redistribution and Downward Mobility So far, we have been using the question on whether state should reduce gap in income between the rich and the poor as measure of support for redistribution. In Table 9, we consider alternative dependent variables: whether state should guarantee employment, whether state should guarantee low prices of basic goods, whether poverty is caused by injustice in society, and whether market economy is not preferable. All estimates are positive and significant statistically; they vary from 0.2 to 0.8 percentage point.
Table 10 shows the results using alternatives measures of downward mobility: whether an individual’s household has moved down the ten-step economic ladder since 1989, whether one’s life is worse than most high school classmates’, whether one’s life is worse than parents’, and whether one expects one’s to have worse future. All estimates are positive and significant statistically. Economically they are also large. The estimate in column 1, for example, shows having moved down the economic ladder since 1989 increases support for redistribution by four percentage points. Moreover, not only that past downward mobility increases support for redistribution, expectation of future downward mobility experienced by children does too as column 5 shows. For instance, being pessimistic of one’s children’s future increases support for redistribution by five percentage points. When we include past and future downward mobility in column 6, the estimates remain similar. Table 10. Using Alternative Measures of Downward Mobility.
Analysis of Downward Mobility Experienced During the Recent Economic Crisis We now look at the effects of downward mobility caused by other sources of shocks, i.e., the recent economic crisis in 2007-08, using LITS II. Table 11 presents the results. We use three measures of supports distribution (i.e., income should be more equal, poverty is caused by injustice in society, and market economy is not preferable) and three measures of downward mobility (i.e., affected much by the crisis, responded to shocks by taking.
Extreme measures, and responding to crisis by taking some measures). We find all estimates are positive and significant statistically. The estimates are economically large, in particular when we use whether poverty is caused by injustice in society as the measure of support for redistribution in columns 4-6. Those who were affected much by the economic crisis in column 4, for example, increase support for redistribution by eight percentage points, while those who responded to crisis by taking some extreme measures, which is similar to the measure we use in the basic results, in column 5 increase support for redistribution by ten percentage points. Table 11. Using the Recent Global Crisis as a Measure of Downward Mobility.
Dependent variable: Agrees with the followings Income should be more equal (1) Downward mobility Affected much by the economic crisis Responded to crisis by taking extreme measures Responded to crisis by taking some measures Adjusted R.
Analyses of Individuals whose Actual- and Perceived Incomes are Matched Cruces, Perez-Trugliain and Tetaz (2013) show that people have biased perception of their relative position in income distribution: Some people say they are poor when in fact their incomes are higher than average. Some say they are richer than average when their incomes are actually low.
Incomes may compromise our results. In column 1, we include only individuals whose perceived position in a ten-step economic ladder and actual decile-group of household spending are matched. In columns 2-4 we also include individuals whose biases are at most one-, two, and three decile-groups, respectively. Overall, the results are robust. The estimates are all positive, about 0.4-0.5 percentage point, and significant statistically. Table 12. Using Samples with Matched Perceived- and Actual Incomes.
Notes: The number in each cell is the estimate of measures of downward mobility from a separate regression of supports redistribution on measures of downward mobility using the restricted (the first number) or full model (the second). All estimates are multiplied by 100 for legibility. The numbers in the last row are the R-ratios; in column 4 the first number is the R-ratio for responded to shocks by taking extreme measures, the second experienced labor market shocks. They are calculated as.
Table 13 provides the ratios, which we calculate using the baseline estimates in Table 2. We define full model as regressions with the individual- and household characteristics and restricted model as those without the control variables. For estimates in Table 2, the ratios of all models are over three except column 2, with an average value of R around three. This implies that, on average, the selection on unobservables has to be at least three times stronger than the selection on observables to explain away the estimated regression coefficients of the past events on attitudes towards redistribution. Thus, it is plausible to assume that it is unlikely the estimates are affected by the omitted variable bias.
Conclusion Downward mobility increases support for redistribution, but only if it is severe: There is no evidence that being unemployed increases support for redistribution. However, being unemployed and responding to the shocks by taking extreme measures does—one year of the latter type increases support for redistribution by about three percent. The timing of downward mobility matters too (recent bad years matter more than earlier bad years do), so does its persistence (more persistent shocks matter more than occasional ones). For examples, one bad-year in the most recent four years increases support for redistribution about three times as large as the average effect and experiencing nine bad years or more increases support for redistribution by about 12-17 times larger than the average effect. These basic results are robust to systematic biases that people may have when they evaluate their preferences for redistribution (Cruces, Perez-Trugliain and Tetaz, 2013). Our tests to explore the effect of measurement errors in people’s subjective responses toward redistribution (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2005; Fong, 2007), and the possibility of omitted variable bias, judged by the ratio proposed by Altonji, Elder and Taber (2005), confirm the stability of the basic OLS estimates. The results are also robust to alternative measures of support for redistribution, alternative measures of downward mobility, and other sources of economic shocks.
Many papers such as Alesina and La Ferrara (2005) and Ravallion and Lokshin (2000) have provided the empirical evidence for Piketty’s (1995) learning model, but we believe this paper adds to the literature in a number of ways. One, we provide a richer picture of how mobility experiences shape individual preferences towards redistributive policies. Two, we show that support for redistribution is not static or sluggish; rather it responds to severe, recent, and persistent mobility experiences. Three, we highlight the importance of the particulars of downward mobility experiences, their intensity, timing, and persistence as determinants of support for redistribution, which calls for a refinement of Piketty’s (1995) learning model. A limitation of this paper is that our measures of downward mobility are not exogenous. If there is an unobserved factor that positively correlates with both downward mobility and support for redistribution (for example, if people who are more likely to be unemployed are also more likely to support redistribution), our OLS estimates will be too big. The Altonji, Elder, and Taber’s (2005) statistic, however, indicates these problems probably are modest, if there are any. Besides, downward mobility caused by a global crisis or structural reforms are, to some extent, beyond the control of any individual in our sample. Two, people may have systematic biases when they evaluate their relative income, but we address this concern by analysing downward mobility using sub-samples of people whose biases are small. Three, downward mobility, which we define using retrospective information, may be unreliable—a concern that we have no answer to. But, perhaps, recalling the years when we experienced economic shocks, especially when the shocks are severe, is etched in our memory and so less likely to be unreliable. Our basic results suggest that this is a possibility.
References Alesina, A. and Angeletos, G.M. 2005. “Fairness and redistribution: US vs. Europe,” American Economic Review 95, 913-935.
Alesina, A. and La-Ferrara, E. L. 2005. “Preferences for Redistribution in the Land of Opportunities,” Journal of Public Economics 89, 897-931.http://www.mythingswp7.com/kjlw/
Alesina, A. and Glaeser, E. 2004. “Fighting Poverty in the US and Europe: A World of Difference,” Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
Alesina, Alberto, and Nicola Fuchs-Schuendeln. 2007. Good Bye Lenin (or not?) – The Effect of Communism on People?s Preferences. American Economic Review 97: 15071528.
Altonji J. G., Elder T. E., Taber C. R. 2005. Selection on Observed and Unobserved Variables: Assessing the Effectiveness of Catholic Schools. Journal Political Economy 113, 151-184.
Angrist, J., and S. Pischke. 2008. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricists’ Companion, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Benabou, R., Ok, E., 2001a. Social mobility and the demand for redistribution: the POUM hypothesis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2), 447–487.
Benabou, R. and Tirole, J. .2005. “Belief in a just world and redistributive politics,” NBER Working Paper 11208.
Corneo, Giacomo. 2001. “Inequality and the State: Comparing US and German Preferences.” Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 2001(63/64): 283–96.
Corneo, G., Gruner, H.P. 2002. “Individual preferences for political redistribution,” Journal of Public Economics 83, 83-107.
Cruces, G.; Perez-Truglia, R. and Tetaz, Martin. 2013. “Biased Perceptions of Income Distribution and Preferences for Redistribution: Evidence from a Survey Experiment,” Journal of Public Economics 98, 100-112.
Fong, C., 2001. Social Preferences, Self-Interest and the Demand for Re-distribution. Journal of Public Economics 822, 225-246.
Fong, Christina M. 2007. “Evidence from an Experiment on Charity to Welfare Recipients: Reciprocity, Altruism and the Empathic Responsiveness Hypothesis.” Economic Journal, 117(522): 1008–24.
Gimpelson, V. and Lippoldt, D. 1996. “Labor Restructuring in Russian Enterprises. A Case Study,” OECD, Paris.
Gimpelson, V. and Lippoldt, D. 1997. “Labor Turnover in the Russian Federation,” in D. Lippoldt (edited) Labor Market Dynamics in the Russian Federation, OECD, Paris.
Goskomstat (1997), Statistical Bulletin, No. 8 (37), Moscow: Goskomstat.
Grosjean, Pauline. 2011. “The Weight of History in European Cultural Integration: a Gravity Approach, American Economic Review, Papers & Proceedings 2011, 101:3, 50408.
Kapstein E.B. & Madelbaum M. 1997. Sustaining the Transition: The Social Safety Net in Post-Communist Europe, Council on Foreign Relations, New York.
Life in Transition Survey (LiTS) I. 2006. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD)
Life in Transition Survey (LiTS) II. 2011. European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD)
Mikhalev, V. (edited) .2003. Inequality and Social Structure during the Transition, Palgrave-Macmillan, Basingstoke.
Piketty, T. 1995. Social mobility and redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 551-584.
Szelenyi, I. and E. Kostello. 1996. “The market transition debate.” American Journal of Sociology 101, 4: 1082-96.
World Bank. 2008. Growth, Poverty and Inequality, Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Europe and Central Asia Region.
相關文章
UKthesis provides an online writing service for all types of academic writing. Check out some of them and don't hesitate to place your order.